Playing the Ostrich on Price Inflation

3

By the time you read this, there’s a good chance that Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke will have held the Fed’s first press conference following a meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee—the Fed committee that controls monetary policy. Leading up to this historic moment, the popular press has repeated a well-rehearsed rhetorical dance as it reports on the monthly release of the Consumer Price Index. Those who should know better repeat the mantra that, while food and energy prices may have increased, so-called core inflation—the prices of everything else in the market basket—remain flat as a pancake. Word on the street is that in March inflation cooled to such an extent that some analysts suggest Ben Bernanke is exactly right to have ignored price inflation as a potential economic problem.

Unfortunately, things are not as rosy as we are being told.

Last month, the CPI rose half a percent. If it continues at this rate, overall consumer prices would increase 6 percent over the next year. That is nothing at which to yawn. Moreover, normal people who live their lives outside the Beltway know that the prices of the goods they buy are generally rising. They do not have to wait to be told by the experts. Indeed as the great Austrian economist, Ludwig von Mises, pointed out, “A judicious housewife knows much more about price changes as far as they affect her own household than the statistical averages can tell … If she ‘measures’ the changes for her personal appreciation by taking the prices of only two or three commodities as a yardstick, she is no less ‘scientific’ and no more arbitrary than the sophisticated mathematicians in choosing their methods for the manipulation of the data of the market.”

The fact of the matter is that core CPI has been increasing at a relatively low rate, 0.1 percent in March, because of the housing market. Prices related to shelter make up 31 percent of CPI. Between 2002 and 2006, a staggering excess supply of houses was produced. Twelve million new homes were built while the number of households increased by only seven million. So many houses and apartments were made during the housing bubble that housing prices remain flat or falling almost everywhere you look.

Falling housing prices, however, do not decrease the cost of living for those people who are staying put. Those who do not need to buy a house are not helped by lower housing prices, especially if prices rise on everything else.

And indeed they are. Food and beverage prices increased at an annual rate of 8.4 percent. Prices of household fuel and utilities, the housing expenses that everyone does have, rose at an annual rate of 7.2 percent. Transportation prices, which include prices of automobiles, gasoline, and public transportation, rose at an annual rate of 26.4 percent. The rise in healthcare prices was relatively low at an annual rate of 2.4 percent. The only truly bright spot for households is that prices for clothing fell at an annual rate of 6 percent. Prices of wholesale goods are also on the rise. The producer price index increased 0.7 percent last month, which implies an annual inflation rate of 8.4 percent.

Randall Holcombe, DeVoe Moore Professor of Economics at Florida State University, is right to remind us that we should be careful about making long-term predictions based on a single month’s data. But as he notes, the trend is up: “In the seven months from March 2010 through October 2010 the CPI rose 0.5 percent. The five months from October 2010 to March 2011 saw the CPI rise by 2.2 percent. That’s a 5.3 percent annual rate of inflation over the past five months.”

Finally, some of those responsible are beginning to notice their inflationary ways are having an impact on prices. Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank President Charles Plosser is now talking about taking the foot off the monetary accelerator. Richmond Federal Reserve President Jeffrey Lacker recently warned that the Fed should not be too slow in tightening monetary policy. Unfortunately, he is not a voting member of the Federal Open Market Committee this year. Kansas City Fed President Thomas Hoenig said recently that interest-rate hikes should come soon. Chicago Fed President Charles Evans, however, is still content with the conventional wisdom that underlying inflation remains low.

Of course, all of this talk about constraining inflation is a little late in coming and somewhat disingenuous, even if Mr. Bernanke announces a change of course in Fed policy. None of this price inflation had to happen. It is the necessary consequence of the Fed itself increasing the money supply. The Fed did not have to act to engage in any money printing at all. And yet, all of the above-mentioned Fed presidents cheered on Bernanke’s massive increase in the monetary base as a good and proper response to the Great Recession. If the Fed had instead allowed capital malinvestment to be liquidated, the economy would be in better shape now than it is. Sadly, it is not.

Share.

About Author

Dr. Shawn Ritenour is a professor of economics at Grove City College, contributor to The Center for Vision & Values, and author of "Foundations of Economics: A Christian View."

  • This reminds me of the old joke, “An economist falls down a well. How does he get out? First, he assumes a ladder.” It appears that differing starting assumptions on the part of people who (we hope) are all prudent economists can result in completely different outcomes. Is economics a reliable science or should we just appoint a witch doctor as the next Chairman of the Fed?

  • HomeschoolNfpDad

    Most economists aren’t as dumb as Ben Bernanke. Many economists have political axes to grind — just like the rest of us. But Bernanke — and Greenspan before him — seem actually to have ideological axes because they’ve been playing the same Ponzi game through different political regimes now for more than 20 years.

    Maybe the only thing that’s really dumb about Bernanke, though, is his luck. Greenspan’s Ponzi scheme should have blown up long before it did, and around 2000, it almost did. The housing bubble is just more democratic than the tech bubble because everybody has to live somewhere. The irony of the housing bubble is that for people who have lost a house, their housing costs may have actually gone up — and that ignoring the loss of the house itself. This is because losing a house generally forces you into the rental market — along with a few million of your new competitors for rental properties. While this probably doesn’t help many landlords renting luxury, vacation or similar properties, it does create upward pressure on rents due to the increased demand for rental units.

    Thus, the observation that “[p]rices related to shelter make up 31 percent of CPI” is itself distorted because prices related to shelter constitute a weighted average of costs associated with home ownership, on the one hand, and rent, on the other hand. In many places rents have shot up. In others, they have remained flat even as home prices drop. In very few places have monthly rents dropped on properties suitable families. Indeed, even people who stay put (probably because the values of their homes have dropped precipitously) do realize a significant benefit from the reduction in assessed values that drive property taxes. Many jurisdictions have been forced to drop housing assessments, if only to reflect the actual market prices achieved by those who manage to sell a home. Thus, staying put can be a good idea economically, if only because taxes are lower.

    Anything that averages a basket of goods will miss the true impact of pricing changes on an individual family. Indeed, the very notion of averaging a basket of goods to calculate inflation follows the same methodology as, well, the rhythm method for birth regulation. Rhythm doesn’t work because there’s no such thing as an average woman, and applying averages to a specific case is always a bad idea.

    NFP, on the other hand, does work because it applies the observations that a specific woman makes about herself. So also the example for Ludwig von Mises: “A judicious housewife knows much more about price changes as far as they affect her own household than the statistical averages can tell.” This is because the judicious housewife observes her own circumstances and then does the best she can accordingly.

    Perhaps the real irony here is that the same people who rightfully mock rhythm and most wrongfully mock NFP (and this category is broad enough to include most conservative Evangelicals, by the way) are foisting the economic equivalent of calendar rhythm upon a population of more than 300 million.

    Dumb, dumb, dumb. We, at least, can be smarter if we choose to understand this.

  • I buy new clothes probably twice a year but I buy gas and groceries every week or two. So factoring in the drop in clothing prices to my basket of goods doesn’t make much sense to me. Clothing prices could double and I’d hardly notice (I’d just buy more at the thrift store) but a 10% increase in the price of coffee is painful.

    I’m on a fixed but still decent income and I’m feeling pinched in this economy, all the while the government keeps assuring me that inflation is virtually flat. Somebody’s barometer is off, and I don’t think it’s mine, since I know what the prices are at the store. I think a witch doctor with some chicken entrails could provide a better augury than the esteemed gentlemen in charge of our economy.